The microsimulation model

MEDUSA allows to develop distributional analyses based in the following overnight effect microsimulation model. The model is built up with the microdata from the Household Budget Survey, a common statistic in all EU countries which is increasingly standardized and which has relevant potential due the large amount of socioeconomic information that it collects. The HBS provides information about household final consumption expenditure on goods and services and information on some socioeconomic and demographic characteristics of each household. The HBS provides information at two levels: one for households and their expenditures and the other for household members.

In order to have a suitable database for the model, some adjustments are necessary. Firstly, some socio-economic variables have been renamed and new ones have been created based on the information collected in the survey (e.g. income variables: decile and quintile). Secondly, it is usual that expenditure variables by COICOP categories have to be aggregated because it is sometimes difficult to have price impacts at such a disaggregated level. To adjust the consumption expenditure data to the inputs provided by the price model, we include in the package a function that allows the aggregation of variables (the aggregation is determined by default but can also be customized according to the user’s needs). Moreover, if the inputs of the price shock are determined by a macro model, an additional adjustment is necessary. In fact, despite the fact that the HBS covers a representative sample of the population and provides a very detailed image of the annual consumption of households, the aggregate costs of the survey are not aligned with the principles and data of the National Accounting, which builds its macroeconomic aggregates based on more complete sources of information. Therefore, before the simulation, the HBS data should be adjusted to make them consistent with the macroeconomic dimension. For this purpose, the package has a function that allows the survey to be elevated to make it consistent with the National Accounts. The following adjustments are made within the function: i) Scaling the HBS population to be consistent with the reference population of the National Accounts and ii) Scaling the HBS consumption data according to the final consumption per energy good of the National Accounts.

The model simulates the changes in spending in the COICOP categories, multiplying the changes in prices by the current levels of spending on the different products consumed by households that are part of the HBS dataset. Thus, the model reflects the direct impacts of the selected price shock before assuming any changes in behaviour related to the new prices. In other words, the microsimulation model does not reflect the reaction of the different types of households to the expected changes in prices. In order to carry out a “behavioural” impact study, it would be necessary to collect the direct reactions of consumers (through the price elasticities of demand for goods) and the induced reactions (through cross-elasticities and income elasticities). At the distributional level the lack of elasticities would not have a large effect because if the elasticity introduced is homogeneous for all households it will not affect the differences between different types of households. However, in future updates of the model it would be interesting to introduce heterogeneous household elasticities. Also, in the case of energy goods and transportation services, these effects are known to be small in the short and medium term, since households do not easily change their behaviour as far as energy consumption is concerned (Labandeira et al., 2017).

The results derived from the model are presented as the relative impact (%) on total equivalent consumption expenditure [1]. The relative impact, Δehs\Delta e_h^s, shows the additional cost that household h would assume in a proposed scenario in relative terms (%), compared to the initial household expenditure, and it is calculated as:

Δehs=cec,h(1+Δpcs)cec,hcec,h×100\Delta e_h^s = \frac{ \sum_c e_{c,h} (1+\Delta p_c^s) - \sum_c e_{c,h} }{ \sum_c e_{c,h} } \times 100

here ec,he_{c,h} refers to the total spending on each consumption category, c , consumed by each of the household, in the baseline scenario and Δpcs\Delta p_c^s is the increase in prices by consumption category and scenario obtained with the price model.

The great granularity of the data contained in the HBS allows the integration of the intersectional approach [2] in the analysis. The results can therefore be calculated according to numerous socioeconomic characteristics of the households (such as, class, gender, race…). Furthermore, in order to facilitate the analysis of the results, the package allows the generation of summary graphs of the distributional impacts either for one or several socio-economic variables.

[1]Equivalent consumption expenditure is used instead of income as it is considered a better proxy for permanent household income since it fluctuates less in the long run (Goodman & Oldfield, 2004). The equivalent spending is calculated based on household spending relativized by the modified OECD equivalence scale, thus considering the economies of scale generated in households based on their size. The modified OECD scale values 1 for the reference person in the household, 0.5 for other people aged 14 or over, and 0.3 for other people under 14 years of age.

[2] Intersectionality refers to the fact that the privileges or oppression of each individual depend on the multiple social categories to which he or she belongs, which are social constructs and can change over time (Cho et al., 2013; Crenshaw, 1994; Davis, 2008; Djoudi et al., 2016; Kaijser & Kronsell, 2014). Intersectionality is therefore also a tool for analysing the articulation of different socio-economic categories (e.g. class, gender, race, etc.) rather than considering them as independent forms of power relations (Colombo & Rebughini, 2016).

References

[R1] Labandeira, X., Labeaga, J., & López-Otero, X. (2017). A meta-analysis on the price elasticity of energy demand. Energy Policy , 102 ( C), 549–568.

[R2] Goodman, A., & Oldfield, Z. (2004). Permanent differences? Income and expenditure inequality in the 1990s and 2000s (Research Report R66). IFS Report. https://doi.org/10.1920/re.ifs.2004.0066

[R3] Cho, S., Crenshaw, K. W., & McCall, L. (2013). Toward a Field of Intersectionality Studies: Theory, Applications, and Praxis. Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society, 38(4), 785–810. https://doi.org/10.1086/669608

[R4] Crenshaw, K. W. (1994). Mapping the Margins: Intersectionality, Identity Politics, and Violence Against Women of Color. In The Public Nature of Private Violence. Routledge. [R5] Davis, K. (2008). Intersectionality as buzzword: A sociology of science perspective on what makes a feminist theory successful. Feminist Theory, 9(1), 67–85. https://doi.org/10.1177/1464700108086364

[R6] Djoudi, H., Locatelli, B., Vaast, C., Asher, K., Brockhaus, M., & Basnett Sijapati, B. (2016). Beyond dichotomies: Gender and intersecting inequalities in climate change studies. Ambio, 45(3), 248–262. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13280-016-0825-2

[R7] Kaijser, A., & Kronsell, A. (2014). Climate change through the lens of intersectionality. Environmental Politics, 23(3), 417–433. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644016.2013.835203